There are two doors. Behind Door Number One is a completely sealed room, with a regular, gasoline-fueled car. Behind Door Number Two is an identical, completely sealed room, with an electric car. I’m guessing you chose the Door Number Two, with the electric car, right? Door Number One is a fatal choice—who would ever want to breathe those fumes? This is the choice the world is making right now.
Arnold Schwarzenegger
This statement made by the California governor in 2015 echoes a general sentiment of advocates of climate change policy. It also resembles a decision that must be made by every car buyer: to buy or not to buy an electric vehicle. Since their mass introduction in 2012, electric vehicles have provided the general public the option to own a vehicle with zero tailpipe emissions. As the electricity grid becomes cleaner over time, electric vehicles represent a pathway toward a zero greenhouse gas (GHG) future. Yet currently, only an occasional buyer chooses to purchase one: until 2018, electric vehicles’ market share was less than one percent, and their current market share sits between one and two percent thanks to Tesla Model 3 sales. Electric vehicles are expensive, and car buyers are price-sensitive. (Electric vehicles generally cost $10,000 to $20,000 more than an equivalent gasoline-powered vehicle.)
Currently, the production of electricity continues to release GHGs, albeit at a lower rate than in the past due to the fracking boom and an expansion of renewable energy generation. Therefore, electric vehicles are not yet emissions free. In fact, prior research has found that in certain parts of the country, electric vehicles are actually dirtier than their gasoline counterparts. The current emissions reductions from the availability of electric vehicles also depends on what these vehicles are replacing. Had electric vehicles not existed, what would the vehicle fleet look like? One could imagine that all existing electric vehicles would have been hybrids, and since hybrids are generally low-emitting vehicles, it may be that the current emissions benefits from electrics are small.
In an RFF working paper, my colleagues Shanjun Li (Cornell University), Jianwei Xing (Peking University), and I explore this issue for the US new vehicles market. To determine what vehicles are being replaced by electrics, we built a state-of-the-art discrete choice new vehicle demand model that includes all vehicle models available during 2010–2014. This type of model allows us to simulate market shares of new vehicles under hypothetical scenarios, such as a setting where electric vehicles do not exist. Our panel of data allows us to identify consumer preferences for plug-in electric and fully electric vehicles since we observe household purchase decisions during years when these vehicles did not exist (2010–2011) as well as their entry into the new vehicles market (2012–2014). We also utilize a detailed household survey dataset called the New Vehicle Customer Survey (administered by MaritzCX) to pin down how households decide which vehicles to buy. These data include “second choice” information on what households would have bought had their purchased vehicle not been available. The second choice data are ideal for assessing what types of cars electric vehicles replace. From these data, we should be able to see which gasoline-powered vehicles are stated as second choices. Table 1 presents popular second choice vehicles for a sample of the plug-in electric and electric vehicles in our sample.
Table 1. Most Popular Second Choices for Plug-In Hybrid and Electric Vehicle Buyers, 2012–2014
As Table 1 shows, a large majority of the second choice vehicles are also either plug-in hybrids or electrics. These data suggest that electric vehicle buyers are quite special in that they have a strong preference for owning an electric vehicle relative to the new car buyer population. We could simply use the non-electric responses to construct a “composite” gasoline vehicle as an option that would have been bought, but this strong sample selection would likely provide a biased measure of what vehicles these buyers would have bought had their electric not been available. Instead, my coauthors and I estimated a discrete choice model that uses the second choice data. Using the estimate from our discrete choice model, we are able to run counterfactual simulations—alternate realities for assessing “what if” questions—where we remove all electric vehicles from the new vehicle market to see which vehicles would have been bought had they not been introduced in 2012 through 2014. Our model also allows us to run a series of additional counterfactual simulations to address other relevant questions related to electric vehicle policy, including estimating the effects of federal electric vehicle tax credits and simulating the effects of alternative subsidy designs with equity concerns in mind.
We find that electric vehicles replace gasoline vehicles that have an average fuel economy of around four miles per gallon above the fleet-wide average. A significant but not huge share of electric vehicle buyers would have opted to buy a hybrid vehicle. This tells us that electric vehicles are displacing relatively clean vehicles, which makes sense given the stated second choices in Table 1.
The federal tax credit for electric vehicles provides up to $7,500 for new vehicle buyers. This credit does not differentiate between income levels for new vehicle buyers. In contrast, California has a subsidy program that targets low and middle income households. High income households are not eligible for the subsidy. UC Davis colleagues Erich Muehlegger and Dave Rapson analyze the effect of this program on electric vehicle sales in California. This program has an objective of incentivizing electric vehicles, but with a dual goal of making electric vehicles more affordable for low-income households. Could this program work at the federal level? To answer this question, using our discrete choice model, we simulated alternative federal subsidy designs that match the income criteria of the California program. We found that limiting the subsidy to low and middle income households meets two simultaneous objectives: it reduces the subsidy dollars spent per additional electric vehicle sold, and it is much less regressive in that more of the program benefits flow to low-income households. Limiting the subsidy program to lower income households lowers the subsidy dollars spent per vehicle because lower income households—which are generally more price-sensitive than high-income households—are less likely to have purchased an electric vehicle without the subsidy. As companies like Tesla surpass the 200,000 electric vehicles sold threshold whereby the federal tax credit begins to phase out, discussions in Congress have raised options for how to change the credit, either removing it or removing the cap. Our results point to a third option that should maintain the consumer incentive to purchase an electric vehicle, save tax dollars, and eliminate the regressive nature of the current credit.